The Rise of the Unions
By 1914,
leading families in the United States and Europe carve up the world. They drove the working class so hard that most
became unhappy. They wanted to do something about their conditions. In many parts of the western world came
unions. For many parts of the western world, this is the answer to the powerful
hand of the corporate managers. From
1914 to the 21st Century was a time of strong Unionism in the West.
Labor unions
are legally recognized as representatives of workers in many industries in the
United States. Their activity today centers on collective
bargaining over
wages, benefits, and working conditions for their membership. They represent
their members in disputes with management over violations of contract
provisions. Larger unions also typically engage in lobbying activities and
electioneering at the state and federal level.
Unions began
forming in the mid-19th century in response to the social and economic impact
of the industrial revolution. National labor unions began to form in the
post-Civil War Era. The Knights of Labor emerged as a major force in the late 1880s, but it collapsed
because of poor organization, lack of effective leadership, disagreement over
goals, and strong opposition from employers and government forces.
The American
Federation of Labor,
founded in 1886 and led by Samuel Gompers until his death in 1924, proved much more durable. It arose
as a loose coalition of various local unions. It helped coordinate and support
strikes and eventually became a major player in national politics, usually on
the side of the Democrats.
American
labor unions benefitted greatly from the New Deal policies of Franklin Delano
Roosevelt in the
1930s. The Wagner Act, in particular, legally protected
the right of unions to organize. Unions from this point developed increasingly
closer ties to the Democratic Party, and are considered a backbone element of
the New Deal Coalition.
Most unions
in the United States are aligned with one of two larger umbrella organizations:
the AFL-CIO created in 1955, and the Change to Win
Federation which
split from the AFL-CIO in 2005. Both advocate policies and legislation on
behalf of workers in the United States and Canada, and take an active role in
politics. The AFL-CIO is especially concerned with global trade issues.
In 2010, the
percentage of workers belonging to a union in the United States (or total labor
union "density") was 11.4%, compared to 18.4% in Germany, 27.5% in
Canada, and 70% in Finland. Union membership in the private sector has fallen
under 7% — levels not seen since 1932. Unions allege that employer-incited
opposition has contributed to this decline in membership. The most prominent
unions are among public sector employees such as teachers and
police. Members of unions are disproportionately older, male and residents of
the Northeast, the Midwest, and California. Union workers average 10-30% higher
pay than non-union in the United States after controlling for individual, job,
and labor market characteristics.
Although
much smaller compared to their peak membership in the 1950s, American unions
remain a prominent political factor, both through mobilization of their own
memberships and through coalitions with like-minded activist organizations
around issues such as immigrant rights, trade policy, health care, and living wage campaigns. Of special concern are efforts by cities and
states to reduce the pension obligations owed to unionized workers who retire
in the future. Republicans elected with Tea Party support in 2010 have launched
major efforts to rewrite state laws that encourage unionization of public
sector workers but which, they allege, impose costs higher than the states can
afford.
The
economist Joseph Stiglitz has asserted that, "Strong
unions have helped to reduce inequality, whereas weaker unions have made it
easier for CEOs, sometimes working with market forces that they have helped shape, to
increase it." The decline in unionization since WWII in the United States
has been associated with a pronounced rise in income and wealth
inequality.
Post-war
Many people
on the left and/or within the labor movement consider the Taft-Hartley Act of 1947; for example, a conservative anti-union law that
contained numerous measures to weaken unions (for example, by banning union
contributions to political candidates and restricting the power of unions to
engage in strikes that "threatened national security"). Others feel
that the Taft-Hartley legislation served mostly to curb union excesses. Some
note the unions were further weakened in the 1950s by highly publicized reports
of corruption in the Teamsters and other unions.
The percentage
of workers belonging to a union (or "density") in the United States
peaked in 1954 at almost 35% and the total number of union members peaked in
1979 at an estimated 21.0 million. Membership has declined since (currently
14.8 million and 12% of the labor force). Private sector union membership then
began a steady decline that continues into the 2010s, but the membership of
public sector unions grew steadily (now 37%).
After 1960
public sector unions grew rapidly and secured good wages and high pensions for
their members. While manufacturing and farming steadily declined, state- and
local-government employment quadrupled from 4 million workers in 1950 to 12
million in 1976 and 16.6 million in 2009. Adding in the 3.7 million federal
civilian employees, in 2010 8.4 million government workers were represented by
unions, including 31% of federal workers, 35% of state workers and 46% of local
workers. As Daniel Disalvo notes, "In today's public sector, good pay,
generous benefits, and job security make possible a stable middle-class
existence for nearly everyone from janitors to jailors."
Unions were
responsible for giving its members such things as Life, health, and accident
insurance. They won such things as dental coverage and many other benefits.
By the 1970s,
a rapidly increasing flow of imports (such as automobiles and steel from
Germany and Japan, and clothing and shoes from Asia) undercut the market share
of corporations with high wage rates. The intellectual mood favored
deregulation and free competition, with a lesser role for union rules. Many
companies closed or moved factories to Southern states (where unions were
weak), or offshore to low-wage countries. The effectiveness of strikes declined
sharply. On the political front, the shrinking unions lost influence in the
Democratic Party, and the pro-Union liberal Republicans faded away.
Intellectuals lost interest in unions, focusing their attention more on the
Third World. Conservative, free market business interests, using think tanks as
idea farms, began to fight back against unions, state by state. The climax came
when Ronald Reagan--a former union president in his liberal younger days--broke
the illegal PATCO strike of air traffic controllers in 1981. Union membership among
workers in private industry shrank dramatically, while after 1970 there was
growth in unions of employees of the federal, state and local governments.
Union Density
Union Density a measure of the membership of trade unions, calculated as the number currently enrolled as members as a proportion of all those employees potentially eligible to be members.
Although
most industrialized countries have seen a drop in
unionization rates, the drop in union density (the unionized proportion of the
working population) has been more significant in the United States than
elsewhere. Dropping unionization rates cannot be attributed entirely
to changing market structures. In fact, scholars have shown the tremendous complexity
inherent in explaining the decline of union density. In my opinion, workers are
happier now that they have a 5 day, 8 hour work week and can spend time doing
something other than work.
A broad
range of forces have been identified as potential contributors to the drop in
union density across countries. Sano and Williamson outline quantitative
studies that assess the relevance of these factors across countries. The first
relevant set of factors relate to the receptiveness of unions’ institutional
environments. For example, the presence of a Ghent system (where unions are responsible for the distribution of
unemployment insurance) and of centralized collective bargaining (organized at
a national or industry level as opposed to local or firm level) have both been
shown to give unions more bargaining power and to correlate positively to
higher rates of union density.
Unions have
enjoyed higher rates of success in locations where they have greater access to
the workplace as an organizing space (as determined both by law and by employer
acceptance), and where they benefit from a corporatist relationship to the state and are thus allowed to
participate more directly in the official governance structure. Moreover, the
fluctuations of business cycles, particularly the rise and fall of unemployment
rates and inflation, are also closely linked to changes in union density.
Economic globalization
More
recently, as unions have become increasingly concerned with the impacts of
market integration on their well-being, scholars have begun to assess whether
popular concerns about a global “race to the bottom” are reflected in
cross-country comparisons of union strength. These scholars use foreign direct
investment (FDI) and
the size of a country’s international trade as a percentage of its GDP to assess a country’s relative
degree of market integration. These researchers typically find that globalization does affect union density, but is dependent on other
factors, such as unions’ access to the workplace and the centralization of
bargaining.
Sano and
Williamson argue that globalization’s impact is conditional upon a country’s
labor history. In the United States in particular, which has traditionally had
relatively low levels of union density, globalization did not appear to
significantly affect union density.
Employer Strategies
Studies
focusing more narrowly on the U.S. labor movement corroborate the comparative
findings about the importance of structural factors, but tend to emphasize the
effects of changing labor markets due to globalization to a greater extent.
Bronfenbrenner notes that changes in the economy, such as increased global
competition, capital flight, and the transitions from a manufacturing to a service economy and to a greater reliance on transitory and contingent
workers, accounts for only a third of the decline in union density.
Bronfenbrenner
claims that the federal government in the 1980s was largely responsible for
giving employers the perception that they could engage in aggressive strategies
to repress the formation of unions. Richard Freeman also points to the role of
repressive employer strategies in reducing unionization, and highlights the way
in which a state ideology of anti-unionism tacitly accepted these strategies
Goldfield
writes that the overall effects of globalization on unionization in the
particular case of the United States may be understated in econometric studies on the subject. He writes that the threat of
production shifts reduces unions’ bargaining power even if it does not
eliminate them, and also claims that most of the effects of globalization on
labor’s strength are indirect. They are most present in change towards a neoliberal political context that has promoted the deregulation and privatization of some industries and accepted increased employer
flexibility in labor markets.
.
.
Union responses to globalization
.
In the 1960s, 1970s, and 1980s, many governments in the West allowed corporations to smash the unions in the belief that spreading production over many nations will reduce cost. The families that control the multinational corporations moved manufacturing to low labor cost countries. The overall agenda of the multinationals is to create several common markets around the world. These common markets would control and manage worldwide production.
Regardless of the actual impact of market integration on union density or on workers themselves, organized labor has been engaged in a variety of strategies to limit the agenda of globalization and to promote labor regulations in an international context. The most prominent example of this has been the opposition of labor groups to free trade initiatives such as the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and the Dominican Republic-Central American Free Trade Agreement (DR-CAFTA). In both cases, unions expressed strong opposition to the agreements, but to some extent pushed for the incorporation of basic labor standards in the agreement if one were to pass.However, Frederick Mayer has written that it was precisely unions’ opposition to NAFTA overall that jeopardized organized labor’s ability to influence the debate on labor standards in a significant way.
During Clinton’s presidential campaign, labor unions wanted NAFTA to include a side deal to provide for a kind of international social charter, a set of standards that would be enforceable both in domestic courts and through international institutions. Mickey Kantor, then U.S. trade representative, had strong ties to organized labor and believed that he could get unions to come along with the agreement, particularly if they were given a strong voice in the negotiation process.
When it became clear that Mexico would not stand for this kind of an agreement, some critics from the labor movement would not settle for any viable alternatives. In response, part of the labor movement wanted to declare their open opposition to the agreement, and to push for NAFTA’s rejection in Congress. Ultimately, the ambivalence of labor groups led those within the Administration who supported NAFTA to believe that strengthening NAFTA’s labor side agreement too much would cost more votes among Republicans than it would garner among Democrats, and would make it harder for the United States to elicit support from Mexico.
Jonathan Graubart writes that, despite unions’ open disappointment with the outcome of this labor-side negotiation, labor activists, including the AFL-CIO have used the side agreement’s citizen petition process to highlight ongoing political campaigns and struggles in their home countries. He claims that despite the relative weakness of the legal provisions themselves, the side-agreement has served a legitimizing functioning, giving certain social struggles a new kind of standing.
.
Transnational labor
regulation
.
Unions
have recently been engaged in a developing field of transnational labor
regulation embodied in corporate codes of conduct. However, Robert O’Brien
cautions that unions have been only peripherally involved in this process, and
remain ambivalent about its potential effects. They worry that these codes
could have legitimizing effects on companies that don’t actually live up to
good practices, and that companies could use codes to excuse or distract
attention from the repression of unions.Braun and Gearhart note that although unions do participate in the structure of a number of these agreements, their original interest in codes of conduct differed from the interests of human rights and other non-governmental activists. They believed that codes of conduct would be important first steps in creating written principles that a company would be compelled to comply with in later organizing contracts, but did not foresee the establishment of monitoring systems such as the Fair Labor Association. These authors point out that are motivated by power, want to gain insider status politically and are accountable to a constituency that requires them to provide them with direct benefits.
In contrast, activists from the non-governmental sector are motivated by ideals, are free of accountability and gain legitimacy from being political outsiders. Therefore, the interests of unions are not likely to align well with the interests of those who draft and monitor corporate codes of conduct.
Arguing against the idea that high union wages necessarily make manufacturing uncompetitive in a globalized economy is labor lawyer Thomas Geoghegan.
Busting unions, in the U.S. manner, as the prime way of competing with China and other countries [does not work]. It's no accident that the social democracies, Sweden, France, and Germany, which kept on paying high wages, now have more industry than the U.S. or the UK.
That's what the U.S. and the UK did: they smashed the unions, in the belief that they had to compete on cost. As a result, they quickly ended up wrecking their industrial base.
Unions have made some attempts to organize across borders. Eder observes that transnational organizing is not a new phenomenon but has been facilitated by technological change.
Nevertheless, he claims that while unions pay lip service to global solidarity, they still act largely in their national self-interest. He argues that unions in the global North are becoming increasingly depoliticized while those in the South grow politically, and that global differentiation of production processes leads to divergent strategies and interests in different regions of the world. These structural differences tend to hinder effective global solidarity. However, in light of the weakness of international labor, Herod writes that globalization of production need not be met by a globalization of union strategies in order to be contained.
Herod points out that local strategies, such as the United Auto Workers’ strike against General Motors in 1998, can sometimes effectively interrupt global production processes in ways that they could not before the advent of widespread market integration. Thus, workers need not be connected organizationally to others around the world to effectively influence the behavior of a transnational corporation.
No comments:
Post a Comment